Saturday 15 June 2013

Development of Capitalist Agriculture in India and the Intellectual Origins of the Fallacy of Present Semi-feudal Theorizations

Praxis Paper Series - II 

Abhinav Sinha

Introduction
The question of capitalist development in Indian agriculture has long remained an issue of controversy among Marxist academicians as well as the Communist revolutionary camp. Even after  six decades of independence a number of Marxist academics (Amit Bhaduri, T.Nagireddy, K. Balgopal, D. Venkateswara Rao, Pradhan H. Prasad, etc) and majority of ML revolutionary parties/organizations/groups consider Indian social formation as predominantly semi-feudal semi-colonial. The reasons which, according to them, lead us to conclude that Indian social formation is semi-feudal include the predominance of agriculture in the national economy, prevalence of tenancy, backwardness of productive forces, dominance of usurers' capital, and some even refer to predominance of religion and caste consciousness in the social life as proof of the semi-feudal thesis. However, such analyses often disregard the sanctity of the particular categories of Marxist political economy or use them in an arbitrary fashion. In his excellent study of development of capitalism in Russia, Lenin showed how the same data can be used to demonstrate the development of capitalism in agriculture, which the Narodniks used to prove that there was no capitalism in Russian agriculture, and also, that the stage of capitalism could be by-passed in the particular Russian case due to the alleged egalitarian laws that govern the peasant economy in Russian villages and the alleged homogeneous/undifferentiated character of the Russian peasantry. Lenin also contended that the complexity of the process of capitalist development in agriculture can create a variety of confusions. In our opinion, the semi-feudal theorizing in India is mainly a product of these confusions. We will discuss the fundamental elements of the Marxist theoretical framework which determines whether a social formation is semi-feudal or capitalist. Then we will proceed to a short overview of the economic evidence regarding the relations of production and modes of surplus appropriation in rural India, which will include the question of primitive accumulation and land reforms, creation of a home market and a class of agricultural wage-earners, the question of tenancy, role of usurers' capital and the structure of rural credit, the character of ground rent, evolution and character of landed property, the question of serf/bonded/unfree labour and the question of production for market/consumption.
The Marxist Theoretical Framework and the neo-Narodnik-Sismondian Origins of the Fallacy of the present Semi-feudal Theorizations
Question of Primitive Accumulation and its Fall-outs
Marx in Capital, Vol-III discusses the process of development of capitalism in agriculture and capitalist ground rent in detail. We must start from there and then move to the views of Kautsky and Lenin on this issue. Marx argued that property relations and the modes of surplus extraction determine the mode of production. The essence of feudal production relations is expressed in the feudal rent. The feudal rent could exist in the form of labour, kind and money. Money rent came into existence towards the twilight of the feudal mode of production because it could develop only with a considerable level of development of money circulation and market mechanism. Money rent gave a lot of autonomy to the peasant, who could accumulate capital by increasing production and a marketable surplus. However, Marx clarifies, any form of rent (even money form) is feudal as long as the landlord-serf relation exists; as long as the agricultural labour is unfree; the feudal lord collects rent in form of cash, kind or labour; the peasant is not free to take the decisions of production; the serf/tenant/peasant is not alienated from the means of production; the feudal lord acts as a, de facto, parcellized state with legislative, executive and judicial powers; the extra-economic coercion of the peasant exists; and, the production is done primarily for consumption of the peasant family and the surplus is surrendered without recompense to the landlord, the dominant production relations remain feudal in character. Marx argues further that the dominant criterion for the development of capitalist agriculture is the formation of the agricultural proletariat. This class of rural wage-earners is created through the process of primitive accumulation, which also simultaneously creates a home market for capital. The home market is created because the labour power itself becomes a commodity, the resources of consumption of the peasantry under feudalism is now free for sale, means of production are alienated from the producer and therefore they have to be bought and sold, and now the production is done for profit, for market. Marx describes the process of primitive accumulation in detail and shows how between the 13th and the 16th centuries in England the transition from class complex of feudal landlords, serfs and feudal tenants to that of capitalist rentier landlord, capitalist farmer landlord, capitalist tenant farmer and agricultural wage labour occurred through the intermediary stages of matayers (half farmers) and simple commodity producers. We cannot go in the nuances of the process here due to the paucity of space and interested readers might refer to Capital, Vol-III for a detailed and picturesque description.
The Question of Capitalist Ground Rent and What the Neo-liberal and present Semi-feudal Theorists Have in Common
Consequently, Marx moves on to a discussion of the forms of capitalist ground rent. Marx accepts Adam Smith's definition of ground rent and shows that Ricardo's conception of ground rent, actually is surplus-profit which comes into existence due to the different conditions of production prevailing in different farms, and precisely for this reason, this form of "rent" can exist in industry also; Marx calls Smith's concept as the absolute ground rent and that of Ricardo as differential ground rent. Differential ground rent is actually the surplus profit of the farmers who have less cost of production than the average and higher rate of profit than the average profit prevalent in the sector. Unlike industry (where the average type of production conditions determine the average rate of profit), in agriculture, the worst type of land determines the average rate of profit. Thus, every farm with better soil than the farm with the worst type of soil will get surplus profit, because the general market price will be determined by the worst soil. Ricardo argues that the only form of rent is this surplus profit, which he calls rent. Thus, according to Ricardo, the poorest quality of soil will not yield any surplus profit/differential rent, and therefore the worst soil will not come under plough because any capitalist landlord will not give his land for free. He will only give it in return of rent. Smith, Richard Jones and later Marx showed that even the worst soil comes under cultivation and it yields rent. This rent is actually absolute ground rent and it comes into existence due to the monopoly that exists in private land ownership under capitalism. This ground rent exists even when there is no capital investment by the landlord in the improvement of land, when there is no surplus profit, and when there is no cultivation/agriculture (and the land is used for the exploitation of natural fruits such as wood, timber, waterfall, etc). Marx shows that Ricardo failed to understand this concept because he did not understand the difference between value and price and between surplus value and profit. He thought that if the market price of commodity includes anything above the production price [constant capital+variable capital+average profit (equalized surplus value)], then the labour theory of value will cease to exist. But Marx showed that Ricardo's paranoia is based on a wrong premise, that is, price is value! He showed that the market price of the commodity must rise above the production price to a level as to yield rent (absolute) to the landlord. Thus the function of the labour theory of value is mediated by the mechanism of market. This does not mean that labour theory of value ceases to function. It just shows that in different particular sectors, the profit might be above, below or (rarely) equal to the surplus value, but the total profit will always be equal to total surplus value. Kautsky in his excellent work on agrarian capitalism explains it clearly. He argues, "The value of commodities is only apparent as a tendency, as a law-like movement tending to regulate the process of exchange or sale. The product of this process is the actual exchange-ratio, or the price obtaining on a market. Naturally, a law and its result are two different things." ('The Capitalist Character of Modern Agriculture', The Agrarian Question, Kautsky, in U. Patnaik (ed.) 'The Agrarian Question in Marx and his Successors', Vol-I, page- 188). At another place, "Consequently, the prices of production as determined by the "costs of production" diverged from the values of the products: however, this is only a modification of the law of value, not its nullification. It continues to exercise its regulative function behind the price of production and retains its absolute validity for the totality of commodities and the aggregate mass of surplus-value, providing the basis both for prices and the rate of profit--which in its absence would float unsuspended in mid-air." (p. 202-03, Ibid.). Thus, it is clear that the increase in production price caused by absolute rent does not in the least affect the health and well-being of theory of value and Ricardo went hysteric and negated the existence of absolute rent, without any substantial reason. Ricardo's differential rent can come into existence only when the owner and producer are two different individuals, because, in that case only, the surplus-profit will be handed over to the landlord, along with the absolute rent. Once the rent is handed over to the landlord, as Kautsky shows, it is quite difficult to differentiate between the absolute and differential rent. Lenin, too, in 'Development of Capitalism in Russia' gives a lot of importance to the question of absolute rent and differential rent. He demonstrates the difference between capitalist rent (absolute and differential) and the feudal rent. Kautsky also shows this difference quite clearly, "Capitalist ground-rent should not be confused with the burden imposed on peasants by the feudal aristocracy. Initially, and more or less throughout the Middle Ages, these corresponded to important functions which the lord had to perform--functions which were subsequently taken over by the state, and for which the peasants paid taxes. The seigniorial class had to superintend the system of justice, to provide police, and represent the interests of its vassals to the outside world, to protect them through its possession of arms, and to furnish military service on their behalf.
"None of these concerns is relevant to the landowner in capitalist society. As differential rent, ground-rent is the product of competition; as absolute rent, it is the product of monopoly. The fact that these accrue to the landowner is not due to the latter's exercise of any social function, but solely and simply due to the consequence of private property in land and soil." (p.216, ibid).
Utsa Patnaik has rightly pointed out that the erroneous views of the exponents of the semi-feudal thesis is due to the fact that they, too, do not understand the concept of absolute ground rent, and surprisingly, this is a misconception that they share with the neo-liberal economists! In the neo-liberal theorization, the tenant farmer is considered at par with the cash wage worker, the only difference being that the wage of the former is not in cash but in kind. They completely ignore the fact that the tenant owns his means of production, invests capital, controls the labour process and takes the production decisions. This is due to the fact that the neo-liberal economists are unfamiliar with, rather unaware of, the concept of absolute ground rent. The capitalist rentier landlord (CRLL) is termed as the capitalist farmer; the tenant as labourer (wage worker); and the rent is confused with profit; the share of the sharecropper tenant is arbitrarily called wage (in cash or kind, does not matter!); all this muddle because the neo-liberal economists only know the relationship between capitalist farmer landlord and the wage worker, and they only understand the concept of profit, not rent. Now we can compare this with fallacy of the semi-feudal  theorizations in India.
Semi-feudal theorists call this tenant as the near-labourer who is destitute, pauper, has no control over production decisions and labour process; who is thus "unfree" under the yoke of "feudal" landlords and usurers. Evidently, they also do not understand the concept of absolute rent and mistake the capitalist tenant for unfree, non-capitalist worker or near-worker, almost a serf/bonded labour. They also do not understand the role of usurers' capital in the agricultural production under capitalism. To this, we will come later. For them, this tenant is an unfree, destitute worker, and not a capitalist tenant farmer who owns means of production. Capital must be provided by the landlord and the sharecropper contributes only labour. This destitute sharecropper only gets kind wage and the landlord gets rent (of Ricardo!). But if we look closely, what these theorists call "wage" is in fact the profit of the capitalist tenant farmer; what they call "rent" is actually the profit on the capital that the landlord has advanced, in the form of interest. For instance, Amit Bhaduri conceptualizes the Indian sharecropper as having little or no means of production, with no saving, with no means to survive, so he takes "consumption loan" from the landlord. But in reality this "consumption loan" is nothing but wage advance which is deducted from the harvest share wage with interest. Apparently, what Bhaduri calls "rent" is actually profit on the capital advanced by the capitalist rentier landlord to the wage-earner. What Bhaduri calls "tenant" is actually worker, what he calls "rent" is in effect profit; what he calls "consumption loan" is actually wage advance, which is later adjusted with the harvest share wage with interest.
What we have in the Indian case is this (which will later be shown by evidence): absolute ground rent is taken by the CRLL, irrespective of the fact whether he makes any capital advance to the tenant as loan or not. What he might take in return for any capital investment in the land and production is nothing but interest on the loan advanced to the capitalist tenant farmer. The tenant farmer is not wage worker. He produces surplus with his own means of production, family and hired labour, his own investments on the land leased from the CRLL, in return of rent which is a part of the surplus that he produces over the cost of production which includes his subsistence cost.
Now, capitalist agriculture might be dominated by the CRLL or the capitalist farmer landlord (CFLL), depending on the conditions of production. The CRLL can transform itself into CFLL when through technological advance and improvement of land, the rent is increased so much that the CRLL has enough capital to invest. However, this change is not at all irreversible and the CFLL can again transform itself into CRLL due to a variety of reasons. Utsa Patnaik has shown the volatility of this transformation. She argues that during the Green Revolution, the rent barrier was crossed and numerous rentier landlords took to farming. Now the situation is different. We are having a capitalist crisis in the agriculture in the age of Globalization (which the semi-feudal theorists take as the evidence of semi-feudal relations, but which in fact, as Marx, Kautsky and Lenin had shown earlier, is only the evidence of capitalist development in agriculture, the agricultural moment of the universal process of capitalist crisis). What we are witnessing presently is a shift back to rentierism and shift to other avenues of investment like real estate, usury and speculative finance. In this period, the question of tenancy becomes important, so we will now take up the question of tenancy.
The Question of Tenancy
First of all, one must understand the fact that preponderance of tenancy in the agrarian economy has nothing to do with semi-feudal relations in itself, as claimed by the semi-feudal theorists. Kautsky in his work gives ample evidence from late-19th century England, France, Germany, the United States and North Atlantic Union, that with the development of capitalist agriculture, tenancy became more and more prevalent. He shows that in capitalist agriculture there are proprietor farms (owner peasant farms) as well as the tenant peasant farms. The tenant peasant produces surplus on the leased farm with family and hired labour. A part of this surplus is transferred to the landlord as rent, another part to the usurer/creditor as interest and the rest is pocketed by him as profit; proprietor peasant gets the profit after paying interest on the loan, if any and the capitalist landlord gets the rent. However, Kautsky points out that the proprietor peasant's proprietary rights become only a formal juridical reality with the development of capitalist agriculture. The proprietor peasant needs more and more capital to compete in the market. He gets this in the form of mortgage loan against his property. In return for this loan he has to hand over the ground rent to the mortgage creditor, who can be a state institution or a non-institutional creditor like the usurer. This in effect is the alienation of the producer from land. Kautsky explains it, "The division between the landowner and the entrepreneur--albeit hidden behind particular juridical forms--is still there. The ground-rent which accrues to the landowner under the lease system ends up in the pocket of the mortgage creditor under the mortgage system. As the owner of ground-rent, the latter is consequently the real owner of the land itself. In contrast, the nominal owner of the land is a capitalist entrepreneur who collects the profit on enterprise and ground rent, and then pays over the latter in the form of the interest on the mortgage...the difference between the lease system and the mortgage system is simply that in the latter the actual owner of the land is termed a capitalist, and the actual capitalist entrepreneur a landowner. Thanks to this confusion, our farmers (one can read the present semi-feudal theorists/neo-narodniks in India here--author), who actually exercise capitalist functions, tend to get very indignant about exploitation by "mobile capital"--that is, the mortgage creditors who in fact play the same economic role as the landowner under the lease system." (p.225, ibid). He argues that through this process the proprietor is not transformed into proletariat, but a tenant farmer. He explains further, "However, progress and prosperity in agriculture will inevitably express itself in an increase in mortgage indebtedness, first because such progress generates a growing need for capital, and secondly because the extension of agricultural credit allows ground rents to rise." (p.226, ibid). Such capitalist transformation is often mistaken for the ruin of agriculture and lead some people to call for "saving the peasant". Lenin dismantles this illusion quite clearly and quotes Kautsky, "The protection of the peasantry (der Bauernschutz) does not mean the protection of the person of the peasant (no one, of course, would object to such protection), but protection of the peasants property. Incidentally, it is precisely the peasant's property that is the main cause of his impoverishment and his degradation. Hired agricultural labourers are now quite frequently in a better position than the small peasants. The protection of the peasantry is not protection from poverty but the protection of the fetters that chain the peasant to his poverty." (Lenin, Review of Kautsky's Die Agrarfrage, p.267, ibid). Further, "attempts to check this process would be reactionary and harmful: no matter how burdensome the consequences of this process may be in present-day society, the consequences of checking the process would be still worse and would place the working population in a still more helpless and hopeless position." (p.267, ibid).
Mao's Theory of Semi-feudal Semi-colonial Social Formation and its Incorrect Appropriation by the Present Semi-feudal Theorizations
Clearly, enough tenancy itself is not a sign of semi-feudal relations. Mao has clearly defined what he meant by semi-feudal relations. Mao argued that in the pre-revolutionary China much of the land was under the ownership of landlords, nobility and the emperor; peasants were forced to work as serfs; the foundation of the natural self-sufficient economy were being destroyed but the extra-economic exploitation of the peasantry by the feudal landlord class was intact and it got linked with the comprador and usurers' capital. (Mao Tse-tung, Selected Works, Vol-II, 1976, p. 312-3) Semi-feudalism for Mao was not a separate mode of production, but essentially feudal mode of production in its transitory stage, or form, to capitalism, but a transition which was hampered by the feudal landlords, comprador bourgeoisie and imperialism, and therefore, which could not be accomplished without a New Democratic Revolution. Here what is of cardinal importance is the feudal character of rent, unfree serf labour, the parcellized state in the form of the legislative, executive and judicial powers of the feudal class, the domination of comprador bourgeoisie and imperialism. Evidently, semi-feudal relations are a particular category of Marxist theory and political economy and cannot be imposed on the Indian reality according to one's wishes. Can we say that in India the landlord-serf relation is the dominant form of agrarian relationship? So-called bonded labour does not constitute even 1 percent of the rural labour force. Absentee landlordism is being replaced by self cultivation with hired labour, as we shall see later. And even if such replacement was not taking place, this could not necessarily be a sign of feudalism.

Reality, as Reflected by Statistical Evidence
The area under tenant farming in India has fallen from 12 percent in 1950-51 to 8.28 percent in 1991-92. The unregistered tenancy also is on decline. Sharecropping has become the dominant form of tenancy. Bardhan has shown by his sample survey of 334 villages in northern and eastern India, that sharecropping is mostly done on 50:50 basis (P. Bardhan, 'Terms and Conditions of Sharecropping Contracts', Journal of Development Studies, Vol-16, 1977). This is a huge misconception that sharecropping tenancy is a sign of semi-feudalism. Under sharecropping tenancy the landlord shows interest in the improvement of agriculture. Unlike the absentee landlord, the new landlord often invests capital in agriculture for seeds, fertilizers, machinery, etc. He is not only owner of land but also the lender of capital. Most of the product of the tenancy farms is reaching market today. This tenant production is not for consumption only, either of the tenant or of the landlord, as is the case with feudal/semi-feudal tenancy. Ashok Rudra and P.Bardhan have demonstrated that the so-called attachment/semi-attachment shows the concern of the landlord for ensured and timely supply of labour, rather than the extra-economic coercion. (Bardhan, Rudra, 'Labour, Employment and Wages in Agriculture', EPW, Nov. 1980). The major portion of landlord's income does not come from money-lending but from rent and profit. Share of non-institutional lending was 95 percent in 1952 which declined to 60 percent in 1981-82. Though, it has increased during the last two decades, but the new moneylenders are not professional moneylenders, but other members of the professional petty-bourgeoisie as Basole and Basu have shown in their excellent study ('Relations of Production and  Modes of Surplus Extraction in India', Amit Basole and Deepankar Basu, Department of Economics, University of Massachusetts, Amherst, MA, USA---this paper is available at Sanhati.com). Again, this is more due to the privatization of the credit system and the withdrawal of the State from the credit services. However, this is not feudal-style domination of the peasantry (tenant as well as proprietor) by the usurers' capital. As we have already shown, rural indebtedness itself cannot be a sign of semi-feudal relations, if there is no unfree/servile labour. Moreover, even under capitalism, the labour is not completely "free". All the capitalist contracts are in-built with different amounts of unfreedom as Tom Brass and Utsa Patnaik have argued. The freedom of labour is the general law or tendency. But anyone who takes it literally, is grossly mistaken. So the rural indebtedness and usurers' capital might lead to the intensification of capitalist transformation of agriculture if other conditions of capitalist development are present (for example, commodification of labour power and land, capitalist ground rent, creation of a unified home market, etc.). Lets hear Marx on this issue. He argues that usury exists in the pores of production; it is capital because it appropriates surplus labour, but without having anything to do with mode of production; it reinforces the same mode of production, by making it more miserable, be it feudal or capitalist. Usurers' capital is money capital that appropriates surplus not through controlling/organizing the production process, but through the instrument of interest; it expropriates the producer but does not concentrate them in one large production process and leaves them scattered and as impoverished, indebted petty producer. BUT, usury continues under capitalist mode of production and can even become an instrument of capitalist development if other pre-requisites of capitalist mode of production exist. (Karl Marx, Capital Vol-III, Moscow, Foreign Languages Publishing House, 1959, p.580-599).
Basu and Basole also show that on the whole, tenancy is on decline. They provide ample evidence for this. The share of households leasing land fell from 25 percent in 1971-72 to 12 percent in 2003; share of area leased in to total area owned fell from 12 percent in 1971-72 to 7 percent in 2003; share of the area leased out to total area owned fell from 6 percent in 1971-72 to 3 percent in 2003; share of partly or wholly leased in land fell from 24 percent in 1960-61 to 10 percent in 2002-3; share of lease in land in the total area operated fell from 10.7 percent to 6.5 percent in 2002-03. So there is an undisputed shift from tenancy farms to self-cultivated agriculture with hired labour. Semi-feudal theorists might claim that the tenancy among small peasantry has increased. But this too is not the case. The share of tenant holdings has decreased in all size-classes. In fact, tenancy in large holdings has increased, that shows the absolute dominance of capitalist tenancy. Share of tenant households in all categories has decreased and the share of land under tenancy has decreased across board. In 2003, 70 percent of tenanted land was operated by large holdings (>2.5 acres), that is by only 3 percent of all operational holdings. The terms of tenancy clearly show that capitalist relations have become dominant beyond doubt. Fixed rent (in cash and in kind) formed 51 percent of total rent in 2002-3, which was 38 percent in 1960-61. Harvest share (sharecropping) formed 37 percent in 2002-3 which was 40 percent in 2002-3. Highest tenancy is found in Punjab and Haryana, which are the states with most developed capitalist agriculture. Reverse tenancy has become a considerably noticeable phenomenon in all states. Basu and Basole also show that the recent increase in the non-institutional credit can mostly be accounted to the states with most developed capitalist agriculture (Punjab, Tamil Nadu, Andhra Pradesh). This is because of the fact that this rise in non-institutional credit is nothing but the capitalist privatization and financialization of the credit system. However, still almost half of the total credit in agriculture comes from institutional sources.
Penetration of market in agriculture can also be seen through statistics. In most of the food crops more than 85 percent of surplus is marketed. Marketed surplus in total agricultural production for different classes of peasantry is as follows: 44 percent for effectively landless; 54 percent for marginal; 65 percent for small; 66 percent for middle; and 71 percent for large. The gross capital formation in agriculture (GCFA) grew with a rate of 3 percent between 1961 and 1999, which is a considerable growth rate.
To understand the differentiation of peasantry, which according to Lenin was one of the most important characteristics of the capitalist transformation of agriculture, we also need to look at the data regarding landlessness and structure of land ownership. 62 percent of agrarian labour comes from households that own 0.025 to 1 acre of land. These are "effectively landless"; these households derive 60 percent of their income from wage, and 44 percent of their yield is marketed, which is substantial for this class of landless population. Share of households with less than 1 acre in 2004-5 was 76.6 percent; share of households with 1-2 acres of land was 12.2 percent; share of households with more than 2 acres of land was 11.2 percent. Effective landlessness increased from 44.2 percent in 1960-61 to 60.1 percent in 2002-3; 60 percent of poorest rural households own only 6 percent of land under cultivation. The share of effectively landless and marginal peasantry in total rural households rose to 80 percent in 2003 from 66 percent in 1961; the share of very large farms (>10 acres) declined from 12 percent in 1961 to 3.6 percent in 2003; the share of households with 2.5-10 acres fell from 23 percent in 1961 to 17 percent in 2003; the share of total area held by farmer families (<2.5 acres) increased from 8 percent in 1961 to 23 percent in 2003; and that of large farmers (>10 acres) fell from 60 percent in 1961 to 35 percent in 2003 and that of the middle farmers (2.5-10 acres) increased from 33 percent in 1961 to 42 percent in 2003.

Conclusion
This data clearly reflects the differentiation of peasantry and the creation of a huge class of agricultural wage workers. We have already cited the data relating to the sheer dominance of the production for market, the credit system and the commodification of land. This data also shows the nature of land reforms carried out in India. We certainly experienced the Prussian path of land reforms in which land was not redistributed to the tenants and landless labour; the erstwhile feudal lord was allowed to transform himself into capitalist rentier landlord, or, capitalist farmer landlord. One can provide enormous body of data regarding the marketization of agriculture, development of institutional and non-institutional capitalist credit system, differentiation of peasantry, creation of  a single unified home market, etc. However, unfortunately, available space does not allow us to do so in this article.
Before we conclude, one caveat must be put forward here. In our opinion, the capitalist transformation of agriculture can certainly not be contested with the rigid theoretical frameworks of the semi-feudal theorizations, as the above evidence clearly shows; however, due to the unsustainability and contradictions of the semi-feudal thesis, the whole argument of the semi-feudal theorists ultimately gets stuck on the question of the character of the bourgeoisie. This topic will need another detailed article, but this much can be said: the behaviour of Indian bourgeoisie during the last six decades is in no way that of the comprador bourgeoisie; the Indian state is a peculiar kind of post-colonial (not in the Derridian sense) capitalist state characterized by a bourgeoisie which is neither national (because it does not share any interest with the Indian people), nor comprador (because, it is not politically dependent and a lot of instances can be cited from Suez Canal issue, Soviet Asia Maitri Sangh issue, to the Copenhagen Summit, etc, which show that it has taken independent political decisions in contradiction with the metropolitan imperialist bourgeoisie) and even less, an imperialist bourgeoisie (because the import of capital by Indian bourgeoisie is much more than its export of capital, which undoubtedly has been on increase for last two decades). Then what is the character of Indian bourgeoisie? In our opinion, the Indian bourgeoisie can be characterized as the Junior Partner of Imperialism (not one single imperialist country, but the entire imperialist system); it is politically independent, though economically dependent; its arms are twisted sometimes by the metropolitan bourgeoisie (since, it is junior partner!), but it never surrenders its political independence and performs a tight-rope walking by balancing and counter-balancing its "national" class interests through bargaining between different imperialist camps. The unipolarity of imperialist system can only be a temporary and illusive phenomenon. As Lenin has shown, monopoly is accompanied by the counter-motion of competition and this very dialectic creates the revolutionary situation combined with other factors.
To conclude, most of the ML parties and also intellectuals, in our opinion, need to reconsider the applicability of the semi-feudal semi-colonial theorizations to the present Indian situation and also Indian history. The issue of programme should not be converted into an issue of ideology, as is often, unfortunately, done. If one even mentions capitalist development or Socialist Revolution, they are often termed as Trotskyites, because, it has become axiomatic that any such claim is the negation of the two-stage theory of Lenin. Such line of argument must be avoided so as to initiate an open debate and discussion on the issue of programme.

You can send your comments, criticisms and suggestions at: polemic.mu@gmail.com

Contact: 09619039793